2020年4月24日星期五

《How The Economic Machine Works by Ray Dalio》

桥水基金的大佬Ray Dalio的一个视频,很喜欢解答了我很多年一直迷惑的问题。此文字版本是我从视频里一句句整理下来加以分类,原汁原味。





                                                                     How The Economic Machine Works by Ray Dalio

The economy works like a simple machine. But many people don’t understand it. Or they don’t agree on how it works and this has led to a lot of needless economic suffering. I feel a deep sense of responsibility to share my simple but practical economic template. Thought it’s unconventional, it has helped me to anticipate and sidestep the global financial crisis, and has works well for me for over 30 years. Let’s begin. Though the economy might seem complex, it works in a simple, mechanical way. It’s made up of a few simple parts and a lot of simple transactions that are repeated over and over again a zillion times. This transactions are above all else driven by human nature, and they create 3 main forces that drive the economy.
    
                                                                            Number 1:Productivity Growth; 
                                                                            Number 2:The short term debt cycle; 
                                                                            Number 3:The long term debt cycle;

We’ll look at these three forces and how laying them on top of each other creates a good template for tracking economic movements and figuring out what’s happening now. Let’s start with the simplest part of the economy: Transactions. An economy is simply the sum of the transactions that make it up and a transaction is a very simple thing. You make transactions all the time. Every time you buy something you create a transaction. Each transaction consists of buyer exchange money or credit with a seller for goods, services or financial assets. Credit spends just like money, so adding together the money spent and the amount of credit spent, you can know the total spending. The total amount of spending drives the economy. If you divide the amount spent by the quantity sold, you get the price. And that’s it. That’s a transaction. It is the building block of the economic machine. All cycle and all forces in an economy are driven by transactions. So, if we can understand transaction, we can understand the whole economy. A market consists of all the buyers and all the sellers making transactions for the same thing. For example there is a wheat market, a car market, a stock market and markets for millions of things. An economy consists of all of the transactions in all of its markets. If you add up the total spending and total quantity sold in the all of the markets, you have everything you need to know to understand the economy. It’s just that simple. People, business, banks and governments all engage in transactions the way I just described:exchanging money and credit for goods, services and financial assets. The biggest buyer and seller is the government, which consists of two important parts:a Central government that collects taxes and spends money and a Central Bank, which is different from other buyers and sellers because it controls the amount of money and credit in the economy. It does this by influencing interest rates and printing new money. For these reasons, as we’ll see, the Central Bank is an important player in the flow of credit. I want you to pay attention to credit. Credit is the most important part of the economy, and probably the least understood. It is the most important part because it is the biggest and most volatile part. Just like buyers and sellers go to the market to make transactions, so do lenders and borrowers. Lenders usually want to make their money into more money and borrowers usually want to buy something they can’t afford, like a house or car or they want to invest in something like starting a business. Credit can help both lenders and borrowers get what they want. Borrowers promise to repay the amount they borrow, called the principal plus an additional amount, called interest. When interest rates are high, there is less borrowing because it’s expensive. When interest rates are low, borrowing increases because it’s cheaper. When borrowers promise to repay and lenders believe them, credit is created. Any tow people can agree to create credit out of thin air. That seems simple enough but credit is tricky because it has different name(Debt). As soon as credit is created, it immediately turns into debt. Debt is both an asset to the lender and liability to the borrower. In the future, when the borrower repays the loan, plus interest, the asset and liability disappear and the transaction is settled. So, why is the credit so important? Because when a borrower receives credit, he is able to increase his spending. And remember, spending drives the economy. This is because one person’s spending is another person’s income. Think about it, every dollar you spend, someone else earns. And every dollar you earn, someone else has spent. So when you spend more, someone else earns more. When someone’s income rises it makes lenders more willing to lend him money because now he’s more worthy of credit. A creditworthy borrower has tow things: the ability to repay and collateral. Having a lot of income in relation to his debt gives him the ability to repay. In the event that he can’t repay, he has valuable assets to use as collateral that can be sold. This makes lenders feel comfortable lending him money. So increased income allows increased borrowing which allows increased spending. And since one person’s spending is another person’s income, this leads to more increased borrowing and so on. This self reinforcing pattern leads to economic growth and is why we have cycles. In a transaction, you have to give something in order to get something and how much you get depends on how much you produce over time we learned and that accumulated knowledge raises are living standards we call this productivity growth those who were invented and hard-working raise their productivity and their living standards faster than those who are complacent and lazy, but that isn’t necessarily true over the short run. Productivity matters most in the long run, but credit matters most in the short run. This is because productivity growth doesn’t fluctuate much, so it’s not a big driver of economic swings. Debt is, because it allows us to consume more than we produce when we acquire it and it forces us to consume less than we produce when we pay it back. Debt swings occur in two big cycles. One takes about 5 to 8 years and the other takes about 75 to 100 years. While most people feel the swings, they typically don’t see them as cycles because they see them too up close -- day by day, week by week. In this chapter we are going to step back and look at these three big forces and how they interact to make up our experiences. As mentioned, swings around the line are not due to how much innovation or hard work there is, they’re primarily due to how much credit there is. Let’s for a second imagine an economy without credit. In this economy, the only way I can increase my spending is to increase my income, which requires me to be more productive and do more work. Increase productivity is the only way for growth. Since my spending is another person’s income, the economy grows every time I or anyone else is more productive. If we follow the transactions and play this out, we see a progression like the productivity growth line. But because we borrow, we have cycles. This isn’t due to any laws or regulation, it’s due to human nature and the way that credit works. Think of borrowing as simply a way of pulling spending forward. In order to buy something you can’t afford, you need to spend more than you make. To do this, you essentially need to borrow from your future self. In doing so you create a time in the future that you need to spend less than you make in order to pay it back. It very quickly resembles a cycle. Basically, anytime you borrow you create a cycle? This is as true for an individual as it is for the economy. This is why understanding credit is so important because it sets into motion a mechanical, predictable series of events that will happen in the future. This makes credit different from money. Money is what you settle transactions with. When you buy a beer from a bartender with cash, the transaction is settled immediately. But when you buy a beer with credit, it’s like starting a bar tab. You’re saying you promise to pay in the future. Together you and the bartender create an asset and liability. You just created credit out of thin air. It’s not until you pay the bar the later that the asset and liability disappear, the debt goes away and the transaction is settled. The reality is that the most of what people call money is actually credit. The total amount of credit in the United States is about $50 trillion and the total amount of money is only about $3 trillion. Remember, in an economy without credit:the only way to increase your spending is to produce more. But in an economy with credit, you can also increase your spending by borrowing. As result, an economy with credit has more spending and allows incomes to rise faster than productivity over the short run, but not over the long run. Now, don’t get me wrong, credit isn’t necessarily something bad that just causes cycles. It’s bad when if finances over consumption that can’t be paid back. However, it’s good when it efficiently allocates resources and produces income so you can pay back the debt. For example, if you borrow money to buy a big TV, it doesn’t generate income for you to pay back the debt. But you borrow money to buy a tractor and that tractor let’s you harvest more crops and earn more money than you can pay back your debt and improve your living standards. In an economy with credit, we can follow the transactions and see how credit creates growth. Let me give you an example: Suppose you earn $100,000 a year and have no debt. You are creditworthy enough to borrow $10,000 dollars say on credit card, so you can spend $110,000 dollars even though you only earn $100,000 dollars. Since your spending is another person’s income, someone is earning $110,000 dollars. The person earning $110,000 dollars with no debt can borrow $11,000 dollars, so he can spend $121,000 dollars even though he has only earned $110,000 dollars. His spending is another person’s income and by following the transactions we can begin to see how this process works in a self reinforcing pattern. But remember, borrowing creates cycles and if the cycle goes up, it eventually needs to come down. This leads us into the Short Term Debt Cycle. The Short Term Debt Cycle: As economic activity increases, we see an expansion the first phase of the short term debt cycle. Spending continues to increase and prices start to rise. This happens because the increase in spending is fueled by credit which can be created instantly out of thin air. When the amount of spending and incomes grow faster than the production of goods: price rise. When price rise, we call this inflation. The Central Bank doesn’t want to much inflation because it causes problems. Seeing prices rise, it raises interest rates. With higher interest rates, fewer people can afford to borrow money. And the cost of existing debts rises. Think about this as the monthly payments on your credit card going up. Because people borrow less and have higher debt repayments, they have less money leftover to spend, so spending slows and since one person’s spending is another person’s income, income drop and so on and so forth. When people spend less, price go down.We call this deflation. Economic activity decreases and we have a recession. If the recession becomes too severe and inflation is no longer a problem, the central bank will lower interest rates to cause everything to pick up again. With low interest rates, debt repayments are reduced and borrowing and spending pick up and we see another expansion. As you can see, the economy works like a machine. In the short term debt cycle, spending is constrained only by the willingness of lenders and borrowers to provide and receive credit. When credit is easily available, there’s an economic expansion. When credit isn’t easily available, there’s a recession. And note that this cycle is controlled primarily by the central bank. The short term debt cycle typically lasts 5-8 years and happens over and over again for decades. But notice that the bottom and top of each cycle finish with more growth than the previous cycle and with more debt. Why? Because people push it they have an inclination to borrow and spend more instead of paying back debt. It’s human nature. Because of this over long periods of time, debts rise faster than incomes creating the Long Term Debt Cycle. Despite people becoming more indebted, lenders even more freely extend credit.Why? Because everybody thinks things are going great! People are just focusing on what’s been happening lately. And what has been happening lately? Income have been rising! Asset values are going up! The stock market roars! It’s a boom! It pays to buy goods, services and financial assets with borrowed moneyWhen people do a lot of that, we call it a bubble. So even thought debts have been growing, incomes have been growing nearly as fast to offset them. Let’s call the ratio of debt-to-income the debt burden. So long as incomes continue to rise, the debt burden stays manageable. At the same time asset values soar. People borrow huge amounts of money to buy assets as investments causing their prices to rise even higher. People feel wealthy. So even with the accumulation of lots of debt, rising incomes and asset values help borrowers remain creditworthy for a long time. But this obviously can not continue forever. And it doesn’t. Over decades, debt burdens slowly increase creating larger and larger debt repayments. At some point, debt repayments start growing faster than incomes forcing people to cut back on their spending. And since one person’s spending is another person’s income, which makes people less creditworthy causing borrowing to go down. Debt repayments continue to rise which makes spending drop even further and the cycle reverses itself. This is the long term debt peak. Debt burdens have simply become too big. For the United States, Europe and much of the rest of the world this happened in 2008. It happened for the same reason it happened in Japan in 1989 and in the United States back in 1929. Now the economy begins Deleveraging. In a deleveraging; people cut spending, incomes fall, credit disappears, assets prices drop, banks get squeezed, the stock market crashes, social tensions rise and the whole thing starts to feed on itself the other way. As incomes fall and debt repayments rise, borrowers get squeezed. No longer creditworthy, credit dries up and borrowers can no longer borrow enough money to make their debt repayments. Scrambling to fill this hole, borrowers are forced to sell assets. The rush to sell assets floods the market. This is when the stock market collapses, the real estate market tanks and banks get into trouble. As asset prices drop, the value of the collateral borrowers can put up drops.This makes borrowers even less creditworthy. People feel poor. Credit rapidly disappears. Less spending, less income, less wealth less borrowing and so on. It’s a vicious cycle. This appears similar to a recession but the difference here is that interest rates can’t be lowered to save the day. In a recession, lowering interest rates works to stimulate the borrowing. However, the in a deleveraging, lowering interest rates doesn’t work because interest rates are already low and soon hit 0% so the stimulation ends. Interest rates in the United States hit 0% during the deleveraging of the 1930s and again in 2008. The difference between a recession and a deleveraging is that in a deleveraging borrowers’ debt burdens have simply gotten too big and can’t be relieved by lowering interest rates. Lenders realize that debts have become too large to ever be fully paid back. Borrowers have lost their ability to repay and their collateral has lost value. They feel crippled by the debt-they don’t even want more! Lender stop lending. Borrowers stop borrowing. Think of the economy as being not-creditworthy, just like an individual. So what do you do about a deleveraging? The problem is debt burdens are too high and they must come down.There are four ways this can happen.

1. People,businesses,and governments cut their spending(cutting spending);
2. Debt are reduced through defaults and restructurings(debt reduction);
3. Wealth is redistributed from the ‘have’ to the ‘have not’(wealth redistribution).
4. The central bank prints new money(printing money).

These 4 ways have happened in every deleveraging in modern history. Usually, spending is cut first. As we just saw, people, businesses, banks and even governments tighten their belts and cut their spending so that they can pay down their debt. This is often referred to as austerity. When borrowers stop taking on new debts, and start paying down old debts, you might expect the debt burden to decrease. But the opposite happens! Because spending is cut and one man’s spending is another man’s income - it causes income to fall. They fall faster than debts are repaid and the debt burden actually gets worse. As we’ve seen, this cut in spending is deflationary and painful. Businesses are forced to cut costs which means less jobs and higher unemployment. This leads to the next step: debts must be reduced! Many borrowers find themselves unable to repay their loans and a borrower’s debts are a lender’s assets. When borrowers don’t repay the banks, people get nervous that the bank won’t be able to repay them so they rush to withdraw their money from the bank. Banks get squeezed and people, businesses and banks default on their debts. This severe economic contraction is a depression. Depression: A big part of a depression is people discovering much of what they thought was their wealth isn’t really there. Let’s go back to the bar. When you bought a beer and put it on a bar tab, you promised to repay the bartender. Your promise become an asset of the bartender. But if you break your promise if you don’t pay him back and essentially default on your bar tab then the ‘asset’ he has isn’t really worth anything. It has basically disappeared. Many lenders don’t want their assets to disappear and agree to debt restructuring. Debt restructuring means get paid back less or get paid back over a longer time frame or at a lower interest rate that was first agreed. Somehow a contract is broken in a way that reduces debt. Lenders would rather have a little of something than all of nothing. Even though debt disappears, debt restructuring causes income and asset values to disappear faster, so the debt burden continues to gets worse. Like cutting spending, debt reduction is also painful and deflationary. All of this impacts the central government because lower incomes and less employment means the government collects fewer taxes. At the same time it needs to increase its spending because unemployment has risen. Many of the unemployed have inadequate savings and need financial support from the government. Additionally, government create stimulus plans and increase their spending to make up for the decrease in the economy. Governments’ budget deficits explode in a deleveraging because they spend more than they earn in taxes. This is what is happening when you hear about the budget deficit on the news. To fund their deficits, governments need to either raise taxes or borrow money. But with incomes falling and so many unemployed, who is the money going to come from? The rich. Since governments need more money and since wealth is heavily concentrated in the hands of a small percentage of the people, governments naturally raise taxes on the wealthy which facilitates a redistribution of wealth in the economy from the ‘haves’ to the ‘have not’. The ’have not’, who are suffering, begin to resent the wealthy ‘haves.’ The wealthy ‘haves’, being squeezed by the weak economy, falling asset prices, higher taxes, begin to resent the ‘have not.’ If the depression continues social disorder can break out. Not only do tensions rise within countries, they can rise between countries - especially debtor and creditor countries. This situation can lead to political change that can sometime be extreme. In the 1930s, this led to Hitler coming to power, war in Europe, and depression in the United States. Pressure to do something to end the depression increase. Remember, most of what people thought was money was actually credit. So, when credit disappears, people don’t have enough money. People are desperate for money and you remember who can print money? The Central Bank can. Having already lowered its interest rates to nearly 0 it’s forced to print money. Unlike cutting spending, debt reduction, and wealth redistribution, printing money is inflationary and stimulative. Inevitably, the central bank print new money out of thin air and uses it to buy financial assets and government bonds. It happened in the United States during the Great Depression and again in 2008, when the United States’ central bank the Federal Reserve printed over two trillion dollars. Other central banks around the world that could, printed a lot of money, too. By buying financial assets with this money, it help drive up asset prices which makes people more creditworthy. However, this only helps those who own financial assets. You see, the central bank can print money but it can only financial assets. The Central Government, on the other hand, can buy goods and services and put money in the hands of the people but it can’t print money. So, in order to stimulate the economy, the two must cooperate.By buying government bonds,the Central Bank essentially lends money to the government, allowing it to run a deficit and increase spending on goods and services through its stimulus programs and unemployment benefits. This increase people’s income as well as the government’s debt. However, it will lower the economy’s total debt burden. This is very risky time. Policy makers need to balance the four ways that debt burdens come down. The deflationary ways need to balance with the inflationary ways in order to maintain stability. If balance correctly, there can be a Beautiful Deleveraging. You see, a deleveraging can be ugly or it can be beautiful. How can a deleveraging be beautiful? Even though a deleveraging is a difficult situation, handing a difficult situation in the best possible way is beautiful. A lot more beautiful than the debt-fueled, unbalanced excesses of the leveraging phase. In a beautiful deleveraging, debts decline relative to income, real economic growth is positive, and inflation isn’t problem. It is achieved by having the right balance. The right balance requires a certain mix of cutting spending, reducing debt, transferring wealth and print money so that economic and social stability can be maintained. People ask it printing money will raise inflation. It won’t if it offsets falling credit. Remember, spending is what matters. A dollar of spending paid for with money has the same effect on price as a dollar of spending paid for with credit. By printing money, the Central Bank can make up for the disappearance of credit with an increase in the amount of money. In order to turn things around, the Central Bank needs to not only pump up income growth but get the rate of income growth higher than the rate of interest on the accumulated debt. So, what I mean by that? Basically, income need to grow faster than debt grows. For example: let’s assume that a country going through a deleveraging has a debt to income ratio of 100%. That means that the amount of debt it has is the same as amount of income the entire country makes in a year. Now think about the interest rate on the debt, let’s say it is 2%. If debt is growing at 2% because of that interest rate and income is only growing at around only 1%, you will never reduce the debt burden. You need to print enough money to get the rate of income growth above the rate of interest. However, printing money can easily be abused because it’s so easy to do and people prefer it to the alternatives. The key is to avoid printing too much money and causing unacceptably high inflation, the way Germany did during its deleveraging in the 1920’s. If policymakers achieve the right balance, a deleveraging isn’t so dramatic. Growth is slow but debt burdens go down. That’s a beautiful deleveraging. When incomes begin to rise, borrowers begin to appear more creditworthy. And when borrowers appear more creditworthy, lenders begin to lend money again. Debt burdens finally begin to fall. Able to borrow money, people can spend more. Eventually, the economy begins to grow again leading to the reflation phase of the long term debt cycle. Though the deleveraging process can be horrible if handled badly, if handled well, it will eventually fix the problem. It takes roughly a decade or more for debt burdens to fall and economic activity to get back to normal hence the term ‘lost decade.’ In closing. Of course, the economy is a little more complicated than this template suggest. However, laying the short term debt cycle on top of the long term debt cycle and then laying both of them on top of the productivity growth line gives a reasonably good template for seeing where we’ve been, where we are now and where we are probably headed. So in summary, there are three rules of thumb that I’d like you to take away from this

1: Don’t have debt rise faster than income, because your debt burdens will eventually crush you;
2: Don’t have income rise faster than productivity, because you will eventually become uncompetitive;
4: Do all that you can to raise your productivity, because, in the long run, that’s what matters most;

This is simple advice for you and it’s simple advice for policy makers. You might be surprised but most people- including most policy makers-don;t pay enough attention to this. This template has worked for me and I hope that it’ll work for you. Thank you.

2020年4月23日星期四

《鄧小閑 - 財來有方(转摘)》

   

     自从开始学习财自技能就不断的听到很多前辈提起邓小闲这位可以说是“财自的开山鼻祖”,很多目前的高手都一定拜读过他/她的文章,可惜我来的晚之前听说yahoo关闭了blog之后他的文章就再也找不到了,今天刚看无意看到一位blogger有保留就借花献佛的copy过来作为我投资文章的开篇吧。目前只有一篇,如果有其他朋友有他其他的文章欢迎留言,不多说上正文:
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
鄧小閑 - 財來有方

每年我定時收到股息,對我來說這是非常重要及有意義:
1. 不勞而獲:只要持有優質股票,就會收到股息。不需要朝九晚X地工作,日日看老闆臉色,收工後帶著半條命返家。
2. 公平放心:股息比工資更令人感公平放心,多些股票、多些股息,打工賣命是否多勞多得,當你著重工資時,就會懷疑老闆是否公平,大胸女秘書的工資是否比自己 高;本想「小國寡民,不理世事」,奈何公司一時裁員廋身,一時又合併重組,真是過得初一,未必捱到十五。
3. 改變命運:此話雖有點誇張,但必須明白奴隸獸出賣勞力、尊嚴的生活往往是世襲,若果要改變下半生或下一代的命運,必須把重點由工資轉往股息,由出賣勞力轉變為擁有賺錢機器--大企業的股票。
4. 長期收入:無論年紀有多大,我也會收到股息,即使60歲、70歲,甚或死後,家人也會得到股息,相反公司對你再好,退休後就再無賓主關係,打工仔若理財不善,隨時手停口停。
5. 簡單方便:香港股民不需為股息交稅,股息準時存入銀行戶口,股東可安心花費,第二年又有股息收入,還可能有大於10%的增長,真有「千金散盡還復來」的感覺。
6. 自由及安寧:只要有穏定可靠的股息,不必再担心股價大上大落,今天下跌了的股價,往往是短暫,只要股份能有不斷增長的盈利及股息,股價還是重上升軌,實在不值得為股價升跌勞神操心,担驚受怕。

對小股民來說利用股息過活,實在有點「何不食肉糜」的感覺,克勤克儉才積得數萬元,買股收息,一年才得一千幾百,又有何用呢?
我想法完全不一樣,買股收息,最初的幾年,的確收益有限,十八年前《滙豐》股價約為7元多,現時股息一年也近6元,相信再過兩年,股息就會升至7元多,換 句話最初投入10萬,二十年後,每年股息已相當於從前的總投入,以後的日子股息還繼續增長,再過五或七年,股息的收入又可能翻一翻。現在所提是股息收益, 資產的升值還没有計算。(可看網誌『大茶飯……21)
二十年是一個很長的時間,但時間總是要過,而且耐性是得到獎賞,每年也有股息消費。以股息為主的投資方式也可以很靈活,可以把股息袋袋平安、亦可再投資,或以股息支付孖展利息,買更多股票,這可算是一種簡單的財技。

人低買高沽,賺取差價時,我則努力建立我的資產,製造穏定而強勁的「現金流」。經過幾年時間,我已習慣這種方式,對股價上落已不太在意。散戶面對獲利股份 難免心癢癢,想獲利回吐,再趁低吸納。若果真正做到未嘗不是樂事,但投資者必須明白當中也有風險,股巿往往波動難測,真的不知道伊朗何時會煶練花生油、北 韓無聊放炮仗,股巿就是受這些無無謂謂的消息影響,但這會令《滙豐》盈利減少,派息下降嗎?

過往我和很多小股民一樣,常以本錢少為理由, 不停炒作,鑽硏各種技術分析,捕捉巿塲走勢,以為只要堅毅不屈,努力嘗試,終會殺出一條血路,但這實在是一個「為錢而工作」之法,太過勞累,要求太高,絶 不是「錢為我工作」的方法,縱得錢財亦是勞心勞力的辛苦錢。況且投機炒賣能有大成絶不容易,世上很多窮人都曾炒金、炒股、炒外滙,出色的投機者索羅斯在英 磅貶值一役獲利甚豐,轉眼又失意於俄羅斯的金融危機。

簡單來說,股息為主的投資概念是一個「絶對」而真實的的投資概念,即一筆資金能創造 出來的財富,並可以真實地反映在你的銀行戶口中,受你支配。陸叔(陳永陸)和很多股民都會以手上擁有的股值,和大巿及最初資金相比,衡量投資成績,這種成 績是相對性並隨時因大巿下跌而逆轉,這種「相對」而非「絶對」的觀念使散戶輕視風險,難以避開股巿泡沫。

古語云:「靜而後能定、定而後能安」,與其不斷炒賣,出賣勞力,不如努力建立穏健的「現金流」,一旦完成目標(例如10萬股《滙豐》),你就會發覺錢像是「天上掉下來、樹上生出來」。

2020年4月12日星期日

《书单》


《书单》看到自己买了不少的书籍,都不同程度看过部分内容,为了努力让自己一本本读完然后写下每本读后感。书名从上往下:

"Kindle 里的书单":
1、《君主论》8%
2、《智慧书》42%
3、《传习录》3%
4、《曾国藩》3%
5、《囚徒健身》2%
3、《原子习惯》46%
4、《自卑与超越》100%
6、《人性的优点》18%
7、《货币战争1-4》 8%
8、《红顶商人胡雪岩》2%
9、《刻意练习:如何从新手到大师》
10、《沃顿商学院最受欢迎的谈判课》16%
11、《伟大的博弈:华尔街金融帝国的崛起》
12、《区块链革命:比特币底层技术如何改变货币》

"2022年未看完纸质书单":
1、《孙子兵法》 10%
2、《人性的弱点》
3、《肌肉健美训练图解》25%
4、《香港股票财技密码》梁杰文
5、《财技密码》《理财密码》周显
6、《枪、细菌和钢铁》杰瑞德.戴蒙德

"2020年未看完纸质书单":
1、《中央帝国的财政密码》
2、《Thinking, Fast and Slow》
3、《Common Stocks as Long Term Investments》

"2019年未看完纸质书单":
1、《影响力》30%
2、《中国通史》20%
3、《货币战争3》
4、《聪明的投资者》
5、《力量训练基础》
6、《资治通鉴.语录》40%
7、《施瓦辛格健身全书》60%
8、《信用风险定价模型》
9、《Security Analysis》
10、《The Wealth of Nations》
11、《The Intelligent investor》

"已读完的书单":
1、《水浒传》100%
2、《巨婴国》100%
3、《菊花与刀》100%
4、《三国演义》100%
5、《自卑与超越》100%
6、《富爸爸穷爸爸》100%
7、《证券投资分析》100%
8、《明朝那些事1-9》100%
9、《金融理财原理上/下》100%
10、《高效能人士的七个习惯》100%

"推荐的纪录片":
1、《货币崛起》
2、《无节制消费元凶》
3、《富人是怎样越来越富》
待继更新......